Constrained Fiscal Space For Post-Covid-19 Reconstruction: Consider Postponing Costly Tax Reforms
The destructive COVID-19 pandemic
The
unanticipated external shock delivered to Sri Lanka’s economy in the
form of destructive COVID-19 pandemic has been costly in many terms. It
put Sri Lanka’s economy many decades backward forcing it to restart from
the beginning again. This happened after it began to show the first
signs of slow economic recovery from the disastrous fallout of Easter
bombings of 2019.
COVID-19 disrupted the normal supply chain that had been developed for
internal trade within Sri Lanka and for external trade outside Sri
Lanka. That prevented the local products from reaching markets here or
outside efficiently and effectively. Large corporates, hitherto
considered invincible giants in industry and commerce, were brought to
their knees pleading for government support for lack of markets, liquid
cash and resources to sustain continuity. As for medium, small, mezza,
micro and self-employed who make the largest sub-component of the
economy, it was fatal beyond redemption.
A flattened-out U shaped recovery
By all accounts, all Sri Lankans have been made poorer needing external
support for surviving, sustaining and prospering. Since modern science
has so far not come up with an effective anti-virus vaccination, all we
can expect is that COVID-19 could be brought under control but not
totally eradicated. Hence, the economic recovery from the pandemic
cannot be rapid, known as V shaped, but prolonged, taking the shape of a
flattened-out U, causing innumerable hardships to people and the
economy in the interim before it would recover to original levels. This
is frightening but something undesired to be reckoned with.
Relying on visible hand of armed forces and the bureaucracy
To come out of the catastrophe, the recommendation has been not to
depend on the invisible hand of the private initiatives, but the visible
hand of the armed forces and the bureaucracy. Even the special report
on A New Economic Vision prepared by the team of economists headed by
former Governor Indrajit Coomaraswamy and made-up of mainstream
free-market economists for the liberal thinking Pathfinder Foundation
had recommended that the government should take leadership in
controlling COVID-19 but it should do so without stifling the private
sector as the primary engine of growth and wealth creation. It had also
highlighted that policy action should be ‘pragmatic and free from
ideological bias’.
Cabraal: The pragmatic and ideology-free policy maker
Ajith Nivard Cabraal, another ex-Governor of the Central Bank, in a
series of policy recommendations, had emphasised on the need for a
strong government to tackle a massive human and economic disaster like
the COVID-19. Cabraal is known for his pragmatic and non-ideological
approach to economic issues. In 2009 when IMF was sitting on his request
for a standby arrangement at the instance of the then US government,
Cabraal did not criticise IMF as an institution propagating neoliberal
economic ideas, then known as the Washington Consensus.
Here, he was prompted by two considerations. One was that by 2000, the
Washington Consensus had already died and he did not want to relish on
skinning a dead animal. The other was that by that time economic
policies of IMF had evolved from beyond the narrow Washington Consensus
taking into account emerging global developments. Hence, the pragmatic
and non-ideological man in him caused him to restrain himself from
uttering any slogan that might go against the government’s move for
seeking IMF assistance at that time.
Limited fiscal space for the government
The Coomaraswamy report had justified the government’s visible hand in
tackling COVID-19 pandemic issues because the government needed to work
‘big’ to act effectively to bring a massive disaster of that proportion
under control. But it had highlighted that the government’s capacity to
do so has been constrained by lack of space due to restricted budgetary
environment it had been facing. Hence, the government had relied on
central bank’s unelected power to print money to provide immediate
relief to the economy.
But as I had argued in my previous article in this series (available at:
http://www.ft.lk/columns/Use-of-Central-Bank-s-unelected-taxation-power-to-fill-it-will-bring-cheers-today-tears-tomorrow/4-699956),
it would bring about a worse outcome in the form of inflationary
depression making central bank action totally ineffective. Hence, it is
in the interest of the economy for the government to take full control
of the situation and relieve the central bank of this undesired social
responsibility.
B.R. Shenoy: It is real sacrifices and not imaginary sacrifices that matter
Indian economist B.R. Shenoy who taught economics to many of the leading
economists of 1940s in the University of Ceylon has provided rationale
for not using central bank printed money for long-term economic
prosperity. In a book published in 2004 under the title ‘Theoretical
Vision’, he has made a distinction between voluntary savings and
involuntary savings.
Voluntary savings are real sacrifices made by people by curtailing real
consumption and made available for investors for use in real
investments. For instance, if a man produces 100 kg of rice and consumes
only 80 kg, he makes a voluntary saving of 20 kg of rice in real terms.
This is made available to investors to produce, according to Shenoy,
higher order goods which economists call investment goods.
These investment goods will produce more consumption goods in the
future, increasing the real income of people thus facilitating them to
consume more consumption goods. It therefore leads to a change in the
economic structure and thereby generation of long-term economic
prosperity.
Involuntary savings don’t work in the long-run
Involuntary savings are those savings created out of the artificial
credit and deposit creation by banks with the support of money printed
by the central bank. These savings are imaginary savings arising from
imaginary assets of financial institutions as against the real savings
made by people by curtailing real consumption. Shenoy says that at first
such imaginary involuntary savings can increase output but cannot
sustain it since they are not backed by real production of investment
goods.
Hence, it leads to disaster. As such, relying on central bank’s
unelected power to finance COVID-19 rescue package in the immediate term
is justified. But to rely on it continuously will bring disaster to an
economy since it leads, as I have argued in the present case, to the
generation of inflationary depression. This will force a central bank to
sacrifice all its hard-earned gains.
Avoid inflationary depression
In this scenario, coming out of COVID-19 economic fallout needs real
resources and it is only the government that can supply such real
resources by taxing people. The US based Columbia University history
don, Adam Tooze, in a recent article in Foreign Policy (available at:
https://foreignpolicy.com/2020/05/13/european-central-bank-myth-monetary-policy-german-court-ruling/)
has argued that COVID-19 pandemic has dragged central banks away from
their safe havens of monetary policy and planted them as activist
partners of economic policy orchestrated by politicians.
Though this has been the global normalcy today, it has a limit. The
imaginary involuntary savings they make cannot sustain economic
prosperity in the long-run and prevent the consequential inflationary
depression within the economy. Hence, central banks should hand over the
baton of leading the economy to the visible hand of the government. It
can be a facilitating supporter but not the leading proponent of
post-COVID-19 economic reconstruction.
But for the government to take over the job, it should have adequate
fiscal space meaning that it should have an adequate resource base to
help out affected people to sustain as well as businesses to
re-establish themselves. This is what the Sri Lanka government is
lacking today.
A handicapped government
As I have presented in my article referred to above, Sri Lanka’s
government has been handicapped not only by an emerging constitutional
crisis but also by the distortions it had introduced to the tax
collection system. The government had introduced a series of generous
income tax and Value Added Tax or VAT reforms at the beginning of the
year in fulfilment of one of its presidential election promises. Though
the objective of these reforms had been to catch more people into the
tax net and increase the revenue yield in the long run, in the immediate
time period, it has been extremely costly to its revenue collection
processes.
Short to medium term costs of tax reforms
The Central Bank Annual Report for 2019 has estimated that in 2020, the
total revenue of the government would be at 9.8% of GDP amounting to Rs.
1,560 billion. If the government had been successful in maintaining the
same revenue to GDP ratio of 12.6% which it had attained in 2019 in
2020 as well, the likely revenue in the latter year would have been Rs.
2006 billion. This means a loss in the revenue amounting to at least Rs.
447 billion or 2.8% of GDP. On top of this, the Central Bank’s estimate
of the medium-term fiscal scenario is quite frightening as illustrated
in the Infographics attached to Chapter 6 of the report. This is
presented in Graph 1 of this article.
An undisciplined fiscal scenario
From the low base of 9.8% of GDP in 2020, government revenue will begin
to increase slowly. In 2021, it is estimated to rise to 11.8% of GDP,
still below the level of 12.8% achieved in 2019. In 2022, it would rise
to 13.5% of GDP, well below the planned target of 17% of GDP made in
2018. In 2023 and 2024, the revenue targets are very modest at 14.3% and
14.5%, respectively. This has to be contrasted with the ambitious
revenue target of 17.5% made for 2023 in 2018 under the old income and
VAT regimes.
With these low revenue bases, all other fiscal numbers would be
unwieldy. The government dissavings as reflected in the Current or
Revenue Account balance would rise to a historical peak of 5.1% in 2020
and are expected to be in the negative range in the medium-term, albeit
at a decreasing rate, since then. The budget deficit, according to the
Bank, would rise to 7.9% of GDP in 2020 and remain at around 5%
thereafter. Thus, the fiscal discipline which had been planned to be
attained under the old tax regime is to be sacrificed under the new tax
regime. Hence, instead of increasing the revenue yield, the estimates
made by the Central Bank reveal the opposite story.
The loss of a regular cash inflow
The new tax reforms, while increasing the tax-free threshold to Rs. 3
million from previous Rs. 1.2 million, had abolished two advance tax
collection systems that had been working perfectly up to date. One was
the advance income tax collection made through employers from the
salaries of employees known as Pay-As-You-Earn or PAYE. This was a
compulsory payment done automatically enabling the Inland Revenue
Department to collect about Rs. 50 billion every year at the rate of Rs.
4 billion per month.
The other was the withholding tax on interest income and other
miscellaneous incomes collected at source from income recipients. That
tax too generated an automatic cash inflow of Rs. 50 billion per annum
or Rs. 4 billion per month. By abolishing these advance tax collecting
systems, the Inland Revenue Department has lost a monthly combined cash
inflow of Rs. 8 billion.
Though this was to be collected quarterly from the taxpayers concerned,
an easy tax collection system that had been in place for more than a
decade has been given up by the government for an expected higher income
in the medium to long-run by catching more liable people into the tax
net. This is where the mistake was made by the government.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.